Browsing by Author "Munger, Michael C"
Results Per Page
Sort Options
Item Open Access A 'Good' Industrial Policy is Impossible: With an Application to AB5 and Contractors(George Mason Law & Economics Research Paper, 2021-10-26) Munger, Michael CItem Open Access Breaking the Stalemate: Avoiding Last Period Defection within Israeli-Palestinian Final Status Negotiations through Statistical Modeling(2017-03) Villa, John J.Debates over the Israeli-Palestinian Conflict can be rife with individual bias, distortions of fact and skewed accounts of history. This publication has two main goals: (1) establish a factual analysis of legal documentation pertaining to the “final status” agreements for the West Bank and East Jerusalem and (2) to utilize raw settlements data to model several feasible two-state solutions with the goal of avoiding common causes of negotiation defections. Both ethical and historical claims to the land, while important, serve mostly to obstruct or divert the peace process, as each group makes claims that serve its own domestic constituency but are inconsistent with the basic assumptions of the “other side.” Final status proposals are all too often based upon desire, history, and personal agendas, ignoring the physical realities on the ground. The illustrations I am able to provide will afford a clearer basis for a blueprint of how to get “there” (a final agreement) from “here” (the actual current pattern of settlements and territory). Negotiators face a particularly thorny strategic setting, one that game theorists call “the last period problem.” In the Israel-Palestine context, the Final Status negotiation means that neither side has any incentive to compromise or cooperate, because the negotiations end and the agreement is implemented if both sides agree. But that means that both parties make one last major push for their respective goals, often disregarding their partners’ objectives and previous patterns of cooperation. The idea of last minute defection is best modeled through an iterated Prisoners Dilemma in which cooperating with ones’ partners is advantageous until the final move when defection often provides additional gains with no repercussions. When applying this reasoning to territory-based negotiations the last period is that of a Final Status agreement. There is no incentive to compromise because each party believes that they are in the final stage and any defection will not have negative repercussions. The greater the ability of either party to grab territory enhances the negotiation position for the final round, and there is no mechanism for rewarding a conciliatory stance. Thus the participants act irrationally—as individuals and in terms of the goals of their domestic audiences—by refusing to cooperate, but the aggregate effect is to block any of the Final Status configurations that would make both parties better off compared to the status quo. This “individually rational, group irrationality” outcome is typical of the Prisoner’s Dilemma context. As a result, Final Status territorial disputes can be accurately modeled as iterated prisoner’s dilemmas facing a last-period obstacle: negotiators recognize that the “other side” will always defect in the last period, which causes an “unravelling” in previous periods as both sides attempt to enhance their bargaining strength by grabbing territory or other assets. Good faith attempts to establish a reputation for being reasonable and willing to offer compromises cannot solve this problem, because the “shadow of the future” disappears in the last period. The issue of defection between partners during territorial Final Status agreements is not a new trend. • Nearing the end of World War II, both the Russians and Americans undermined years of active military alliance and cooperation by rushing to grab land during the last days of the war, hopping to strengthen their negotiating positions. • Likewise, throughout the Nixon-Kissinger attempts at negotiation in Paris to sign an agreement establishing a “final” boundary for North and South Vietnam, the North Vietnamese military was being urged by its leaders on the ground to annex more territory. Each new grab of land enhanced the position of the North Vietnamese negotiators, but it also required a constant redrawing of maps, so that negotiators always felt they were starting over rather than making final arrangements. These examples highlight an additional issue, which comes up frequently during Final Status negotiations, that being preemptive defection. The Israeli-Palestinian Conflict and specifically the placement of the Settlements in the West Bank can be seen as a preemptive defection per the internationally disruptive intentions behind each settlement. In the 1970s, Israeli Prime Minister Ariel Sharon popularized the term, “Facts on the Ground.” Sharon’s goal was to establish Israeli enclaves across the West Bank that would eventually grow so large that a contagious Palestinian state would no longer be a viable option. In the 1980s, Sharon made his defection from good-faith negotiating very clear when he said, “everyone there should move [to the West Bank], should run, should grab more hills, expand more territory. Everything that’s grabbed will be in our hands. Everything we don’t grab will be in their hands.” Thus the issue of preemptive defection, as well as final stage defection in iterated territorial negotiations, is the issue that this paper attempts to address. To address this issue, this publication uses a specialized Criteria Alternative Matrix (CAM), a method in which physical realities, such as population, distance, and area, are used to compute composite annexation and separation scores for each settlement, thus displaying a feasible final status border. By limiting each actor’s role in the decision-making process and using tangible data to limit negotiations, there are fewer opportunities for actor defection and the resulting collapses. For the model to be most applicable it is essential to first understand the legal roots of modern Israeli-Palestinian. Simply modeling conflicts isolated from the surrounding political landscape can lead to both inaccurate results as well as unintentional bias. Thus preceding the model is a journey through the legal history of the Israeli settlements in the West Bank and East Jerusalem.Item Open Access China's Internet Governance: A New Conceptualization of the Cyber-Sovereignty Model(2019-04-09) Zhang, QiangIn recent years, China’s Internet governance regime has been subject to increasing literature scrutiny and attention. A rising superpower, China’s vision for the Internet on domestic and international stages has far-reaching implications for the future cyber world order. While traditional theories of governance typically categorize China as a cyber-sovereign nation, I argue that China’s approach is more nuanced and can better be considered under a “flexible” cyber-sovereignty model. Through both a historical and case-study analysis, I suggest that this new model for China better considers the effects of new, rising capital forces—Chinese internet corporations—and explains the dynamic mix of rejection and assimilation into the existing regime that characterizes China’s current Internet governance strategy. Ultimately, this new model can help us conceptualize China’s vision and strategy for Internet governance, which can have far-ranging implications for the future of cyberspace and the Internet as we know it.Item Open Access Desert? You Can't Handle Desert!(INDEPENDENT REVIEW, 2021) Munger, Michael CItem Open Access Explorations of Heterogeneity in Models of Voter Choice(2018) Jenke, LibbyIn this dissertation, I examine three sources of heterogeneity in voter choice that fit into two typologies. The first of these is inter-individual heterogeneity, or the idea that different types of individuals use unique models in evaluating candidates. I examine voters’ levels of moral conviction and voters’ partisanship as sources of this type of determinacy of decision criteria. My results indicate that the morally convicted differ in the shape of their utility function for candidate assessment. Instead of having a linear function representing the relationship between the candidate’s distance from their ideal points and how much they like the candidate, the morally convicted have a convex curve. I also find that the criteria on which individuals rate candidates differs based on whether they are partisan or moderate voters. I use the method of eye tracking to find that moderates tend to weigh candidates’ policy stances much less than partisans do.
The second type of heterogeneity explored is intra-individual heterogeneity, or the idea that the same individual uses different models depending on the context she is in. In an experiment, I find this type of heterogeneity is present: it is possible to prime people to use directional or proximity theory based on whether the issue is presented through a proximity-based framework or a directional-based structure.
This dissertation contributes to the literature on heterogeneity by providing a theoretical framework within which to think of different types of heterogeneity. It also provides something new in each chapter: Chapters 2 and 4 offer the first examination of these sources of heterogeneity while Chapter 3 uses a new method in political science.
Item Open Access Life of the Party or Just a Third Wheel? Effects of Third Parties in U.S. House Elections(2008-04-14) Lee, Daniel JohnHow is two-party electoral competition influenced by third parties, even under normal political conditions? I argue that the mere threat of third party entry into the election induces anticipatory electoral strategies by the major parties. This effect, which is a normal aspect of the two-party system, is how third parties play a consistent role in U.S. elections. The ability for third parties to influence the major parties is moderated by electoral institutions. The ballot access requirement, in the form of a signature requirement, varies widely across House elections and is a significant predictor of third party electoral success. Consistent with conventional wisdom, I find that it has a negative effect on the likelihood of entry. Notably, the requirement also has a positive effect on third party vote shares, conditional on successful petitioning, due to a screening and quality effect. I explore the effects of third party threat in unidimensional and multidimensional settings. A formal model of elections predicts that the threat of entry induces major party divergence in a unidimensional ideological space. The major parties diverge in anticipation of potential third party entry. An empirical analysis of candidate positioning in the 1996 U.S. House elections finds support of this hypothesis. Data on major party campaign advertising in the 2000 to 2004 U.S. House elections are used to assess third party effects in a multidimensional framework. I show that third party threat influences the scope and content of campaign advertising. Major party candidates, particularly incumbents, discuss a broader range of issues when third party threat is higher. I use the case of environmental issues and the Green party to assess the influence of third parties on issue-specific content. I find that Green party threat leads to predictable differences between Democratic and Republican advertising on environmental issues. In sum, third parties play a consistent role in U.S. House elections by inducing anticipatory strategies by the major parties. This strategic framework for understanding third parties stresses two things. First, one should focus on the major parties in order to gauge the influence of third parties. Second, one should not conclude that third parties are irrelevant because of their minimal electoral success. Third party effects are in fact present even in elections where a third party does not enter.Item Open Access Party Power, Constituency Preferences, and Legislative Decision-Making in Congress(2018) Ballard, Andrew OjalaQuestions of party power and legislative outcomes are central to our understanding of Congress. And yet, our knowledge of these concepts has many gaps. We know little about exactly how parties negotiate legislative deals with their members—and hold them to their deals—or about how parties exert agenda control before bills reach the floor. We also have limited knowledge of how predictably the outcomes of bills are, particularly from their content. These questions remain unanswered largely because political scientists have traditionally not had data or methods at their disposal to answer them. In my dissertation, I provide some answers to these questions via a focus on text analysis.
In chapter one, I examine how parties make deals with recalcitrant members on landmark legislation, and more importantly, how members are held to their deals. Particularly, I argue that public statements are a tool wielded by the party, and when members are convinced to vote for a bill they are provided incentive to make a statement in support of the bill to lock them into their vote. Using a novel data set of all public statements made by members of Congress, and two pieces of landmark healthcare legislation (the Affordable Care Act in 2009-2010 and the American Health Care Act in 2017) I show that members of Congress do make public statements after they make deals to vote with the party, and that these statements are likely for the purpose of precommitting to vote with the party.
In chapter two, I seek to quantify the level of agenda control exerted by the majority party on bills that never reach a final passage vote. To do this, I present the first systematic estimates of how members would have voted on bills based on a characterization of bill content from bills’ text, would they have come to a final passage vote. I find that the majority party not only exercises negative agenda control, but also considerable positive agenda control. I also find that the minority party in the House is systematically and consistently shut out of the agenda process.
In chapter three, I investigate how predictable the outcome of bills is and whether bill content has a part to play in the predictability of bill outcomes. I find that I am able to predict where bills end up in the US House of Representatives with high accuracy, and that knowledge about the content of a bill has a sizable effect on how well I am able to predict bill outcomes.
Item Open Access Populism, Self-Government, and Liberty(INDEPENDENT REVIEW, 2021) Munger, Michael CItem Open Access Social Thought and Social Change: Methodological Dilemmas at the Intersection of Science and Ethics(2010) English, William EdwardI argue that ethical convictions are crucial to the maintenance and transformation of social institutions. Moreover, since ethical convictions are sometimes corrigible and open to persuasive transformation, ethical persuasion can be a powerful source of social change. However, I observe that the dominant analytic techniques of the social sciences are ill equipped to understand the nature and import of ethical convictions, and even less well equipped to inform ethical persuasion. I argue this, in part, explains why social science research has often proved of little value in trying to address prominent social concerns.
This diagnosis raises a puzzle and a challenge. The puzzle is why some social scientists would wholly commit themselves to methods that cannot adequately deal with important dimensions of social structure. I show this is due to a misguided conception of science, one which seeks an "absolute perspective" that requires reducing or explaining away ethical convictions.
The challenge, once this vision of science is rejected in favor of a more pragmatic one, is 1) to understand the systematic limits of different methodological approaches and 2) to see how an account of ethics, rightly understood, can complement social scientific knowledge in service of better social outcomes.
I evaluate three dominant methodological approaches in the social sciences, namely, statistical modeling, formal modeling, and biological-behavioral research. Although all are useful within certain domains, I show that each has systematic limits relating to the dynamism of ethical convictions. I demonstrate how these methods can fail on their own terms and can blind researchers to important resources for social change, such as possibilities for persuasion.
Finally, I develop an account of the relationship between ethics, rationality, and persuasion drawing on the work of Hans-Georg Gadamer, Alasdair MacIntyre, and Charles Taylor. This account rejects prominent "scientific" attempts to explain ethical allegiances as biologically hardwired or structurally determined, and it further challenges accounts of ethical naturalism and pluralistic neutrality.
I conclude by illustrating the constructive role that ethical persuasion has played in a number of development projects, which help demonstrate my thesis that debates about visions of "the good" matter profoundly for human flourishing.
Item Open Access The Danger of Party Government(2017) Bennett, ScottAmerican voters understand that elections have consequences, but they have become so disillusioned by their political system that approximately 40 percent have self-selected out of the two-party circus, choosing instead to identify as independent or unaffiliated which often requires them to forego their primary election voting rights. They understand that the process no longer serves its intended purpose of providing for representative government. Nevertheless, when it comes to elections, Americans get it wrong in just about every way possible. They spend so much time debating which superficial features of the electoral system—voter ID laws, polling place hours and locations, voter registration deadlines, etc.—are destroying the political process that they overlook the real cause of its decay: that political parties exercise control over the rules of the electoral system.
At the end of the day, people want a government that works. It is quite clear that the political system we have now simply does not allow for that. Less obvious are exactly why this is so, and what can be done. The role of this paper, then, is as a sort of citizen’s primer to our electoral crisis. I begin by tracing the origins of American political parties and describe how they and their agents in government mold the electoral system to their advantage in getting and maintaining control of government. Next, I discuss the ways in which that system is so deleterious to stable, functioning government and “national attachment” in the body politic. I then propose an alternative electoral system that would allow for fair and effective representation of more people, helping to rebuild the necessary trust and confidence in our fundamental political institutions. Finally, I reflect on the dangers of continuing to use a system in which political parties—private organizations—abuse state power and the fundamental institution of democracy—the election—to protect and advance their private interests, and how institutional collapse might be avoided.
Item Open Access The divergent paths of post-quake Nepal and Haiti – The Hierarchical System for Emergency Mitigation as a determinant for emergency humanitarian aid coordination(2018-03-26) Keefe, CarolineNatural disasters have always been extremely disruptive events, destroying thousands of lives and homes without warning, killing hundreds, and threatening to plunge into disarray entire societies unprepared to deal with the disaster. Since the early 2000s, scholars have been creating several models that have been determined to be appropriate systems of preparing for, responding to, and recovering from disasters, particularly natural disasters. One of the most well-known models is the Hierarchical System for Emergency Mitigation, or the HSEM model. It is considered one of the most adaptable and logical models for disaster management. Using the HSEM model, this paper will compare the preparation for, response to, and recovery from the earthquake in Haiti of 2010 with the earthquake in Nepal of 2015, focusing on the efforts of the Red Cross and USAID.Item Open Access The Effects of Religion and Patriarchal Norms on Female Labor Force Participation(2017-05-09) Nnoromele, ChidinmaThis paper provides an empirical study of the influence of religion, religiosity, and patriarchal norms on female labor force participation across 40 countries. Using micro-level data from the International Social Survey Programme (ISSP) 2012: “Family and Changing Gender Roles IV and macro-level data from World Bank Group’s Women, Business, and the Law 2012 database, the study examines religious and patriarchal aspects that influence female labor force participation among working women, ages 15 to 64. The analysis supports the hypothesis that more religious and socially conservative women are less likely to have paid work. However, the analysis, which examines ten different religions, finds that the specific religion a woman practices, excluding the cultural religions (Judaism and Hinduism), does not influence female labor force participation when controlling for national and environmental cultural factors. This suggests that a country’s institutions, socio-political context, and geographic cultural heritage matter in the way that religiosity is expressed in women’s economic participation.Item Open Access The Exclusion of Conservative Women from Feminism: A Case Study on Marine Le Pen of the National Rally(2019-04) Kiprilov, NicoleThere is a lack of civil discourse and collaboration among women of different feminist identities in the United States and abroad. This is somewhat puzzling, especially because historically, feminism has never really assumed a definitive identity. It has been molded and shaped not only by political movements and interpretations of them, but also by women’s subjective and highly personal experiences. This lack of civil discourse in the feminist arena has excluded women who identify with traditional first or second-wave feminism. What has become a somewhat radical idea is that women who do not favor modern-day, progressive, left-wing, fourth-wave feminism, the wave that the majority of American society is currently in, may still actually favor improving the lives of women. The advocacy of women’s rights on the basis of gender equality is at the core of feminism, although not entirely explicatory of feminism, regardless of what iteration of it is in practice. It is, therefore, not irrational to claim that advocacy of women’s lives may come in different forms, which leads to the idea that it may perhaps still be worth listening to women who identify as traditional feminists. Thus, an important conversation must be started in the academic community about the demonization of the right-wing when it comes to women’s issues. In this thesis, I identify a gap in the academic community: the lack of academic literature connecting right-wing politics and women’s rights issues via a neutral, academic lens. Through a case study on Marine Le Pen, I contend that the phenomenon of Marine Le Pen – her rise to power, her shifting of the National Rally rhetoric on women’s issues from the time of her father’s leadership to her current leadership as part of her rebranding campaign, her stances on women’s issues and how they fit into a more conservative feminist framework, and the resulting support she has received from the female electorate in France – may be an indication that conservative women have been excluded from feminism. This serves as an academic attempt and initial step to mitigate the demonization of conservative feminist tenets.Item Open Access The Political Economy of Public Credit(2012) Salsman, Richard MichaelThis dissertation critically examines predominant political-economic theories of public credit and public debt in light of the origins, development, and recent record expansion in such debt. Using a "history of thought" approach, I focus on those aspects of theory, from three main schools of thought - Classical, Keynesian, and Public Choice - which seek to explain the evolution of public debt, its political-economic causes and effects, the meaning of sustainability in public debt burdens, and the conditions under which governments are likely to monetize or repudiate their debts. For empirical context, I also provide three centuries of data on public debt for major nations, relative to their national income, and government bond-yield data for more recent decades.
There is value in classifying the major political economists who have examined public credit and public debt since 1700 as "pessimists," "optimists" or "realists."
Public debt pessimists argue that government provides no truly productive services, that its taxing and borrowing detract from the private economy, while unfairly burdening future generations, and that high and rising public leverage ratios are unsustainable and will likely cause national insolvency and long-term economic ruin. When public debts become excessive or un-payable, pessimists advise explicit default or deliberate repudiation. Public debt pessimists also believe financiers in general and public bondholders in particular are unproductive. Pessimists usually endorse smaller-sized governments and free markets. With few exceptions, most public debt pessimists appear in the Classical or Public Choice schools of thought. Among prominent public debt pessimists, the most representative are David Hume and Adam Smith.
Public debt optimists believe that government provides not only productive services, such as infrastructure and social insurance, but means to mitigate what they perceived to be "market failures," including savings gluts, economic depressions, inflation, and secular stagnation. Optimists contend that deficit-spending and public debt accumulation can stimulate or sustain economy activity and ensure full employment, without burdening present or future generation. To the extent public debts become excessive or un-payable, optimists tend to advise implicit default, by official and deliberate debasement of the national currency (inflation). As do pessimists, public debt optimists view financiers and bondholders as essentially unproductive. Optimists also defend a relatively larger economic role for the state. Almost without exception, optimists reside in the Keynesian school of political-economic thought. Among the leading optimists, the most representative are Alvin Hansen and Abba Lerner.
Public debt realists contend that government can and should provide certain productive services, mainly national defense, police protection, courts of justice, and basic infrastructure, but that social and redistributive schemes tend to undermine national prosperity. Realists say public debt should fund only services and projects that help a free economy maximize its potential, and that analysis must be contextualized - i.e., related to a nation's credit capacity, productivity, and taxable capacity. According to realists, public leverage is neither inevitably harmful, as pessimists say, nor infinite, as optimists say. Realists view financiers as productive and insist that sovereigns redeem their public debts in full, on time, and in sound money. Realists favor constitutionally-limited yet energetic governments that help promote robust markets. They appear mainly in the Classical era of political-economic thought. The most representative and renowned of the public debt realists are Sir James Steuart and Alexander Hamilton.
My main thesis is that public debt realists provide the most persuasive theories of public credit and public debt, and thus the most plausible interpretations of the long, fascinating history of public debt. Moreover, certain puzzles and paradoxes arising in contemporary public debt experience, among developed nations - including the recent, multi-decade trend of simultaneously rising public-leverage ratios and declining public debt yields - is explicable primarily in realist terms. In contrast, public debt pessimists and optimists alike offer unbalanced, inadequate accounts of public debt experience. Whereas pessimists are too often confused or mistaken in foreseeing an alleged "inevitable" ruin from public debt, optimists more often than not are confused and mistaken about the alleged "stimulus" attainable by large-scale deficit-spending and debt build-ups. Looking ahead, the realist perspective is likely to provide superior guideposts for maximally-accurate interpretations of public debt policies and trends.
Item Open Access The Road to Crony Capitalism(INDEPENDENT REVIEW, 2019-12-01) Munger, Michael C; Vilarreal-Diaz, Mario