Browsing by Author "Pizer, William Aaron"
Results Per Page
Sort Options
Item Open Access A Strategy to Increase Energy Efficiency Investment in Public Housing(2013-04) Kochanowsky, AmyThis document proposes a strategy for Environmental Defense Fund to increase energy efficiency investment in public housing. Improving the energy efficiency of public housing buildings represents a tremendous opportunity to decrease energy consumption nationwide. In 2010, PHA-paid energy expenditures totaled more than $1 billion, a similar magnitude to the $3.6 billion the U.S. Department of Defense spends on energy consumption in its facilities. Reduced energy use results in cost savings for public housing authorities (PHAs) and the federal government, and reduced greenhouse gas emissions. The U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development (HUD) provides utility subsidies to PHAs and oversees their work. Working with HUD, many housing authorities have used energy performance contracts to perform energy efficiency retrofits. These contracts will continue to be an important tool to enable housing authorities to invest in energy efficiency. As a leading environmental nonprofit, Environmental Defense Fund (EDF) has a significant role to play in helping PHAs across the country to invest in energy efficiency.Some housing authorities have already performed energy efficiency retrofits; many others have not yet become involved in programs to reduce energy use. EDF can work with housing authorities of varying levels of experience to help increase investment in energy efficiency nationwide. If EDF is successful in its strategy, it should expect to see housing authorities of all sizes using locally- or context-appropriate funding models to invest in energy efficiency. Working with public housing authorities, HUD, and partner organizations, EDF has the ability to help decrease our nation’s energy consumption and reduce greenhouse gas emissions associated with energy use. These efforts can increase national awareness of the importance of making the country’s affordable housing stock more energy efficient. Implementing the strategy outlined here will help EDF improve the climate, preserve affordable housing for those who need it most, and demonstrate the significance of public housing.Item Open Access An Assessment of Renewable Portfolio Standards and Potential for Expansion in the Southeastern United States(2012-04-20) Jentgen, MatthewWe currently face a tremendous challenge to transition away from carbon-intensive fossil fuels as our primary energy source to more sustainable and cleaner options, including renewable energy. A Renewable Portfolio Standard (RPS), which requires a minimum share of renewable power generation, is one policy mechanism that has been adopted by many states in the US to stimulate generation and investment. The recent passage of the North Carolina Renewable Energy and Energy Efficiency Standard (REPS) represents the first example of such a program in the South. Attempting to learn from this experience, this paper evaluates and offers lessons for other southern states who might adopt a renewable portfolio standard. This work responds to interest by the North Carolina Sustainable Energy Association (NCSEA) on the potential for other southern states to adopt a renewable portfolio standard. Combining historical experience with RPSs, recent experience with the NC REPS, and interviews with policymakers and energy sector stakeholders in neighboring South Carolina, I have concluded that while there are barriers to RPS adoption, there are also tremendous opportunities. There are three elements of a renewable portfolio standard that can be attractive to South Carolina policymakers: 1. Job growth potential: A renewable industry in North Carolina has been bolstered by the state’s renewable standard. A similar industry can be built in South Carolina. 2. A state mandate is better than a federal mandate: South Carolina’s ideological makeup is more inclined to state regulations based on a state’s needs. Other traditionally conservative states have enacted renewable portfolio standards: Utah, Arizona, South Dakota, and North Dakota. 3. Benefits to rural electricity cooperatives: Rural electricity cooperative members in South Carolina have historically been skilled technicians with experience installing appliances and equipment. These cooperatives could benefit from a new industry that installed renewable technologies such as solar photovoltaic and solar thermal systems. While the elements discussed above can drive RPS adoption in South Carolina, the policy design of North Carolina’s REPS can serve as a template to create the next renewable standard in the South. It is important to balance the renewable energy goals with the realities of regulated energy markets in the region. Based upon insights from North Carolina’s experience and general research of renewable energy policies, I recommend four policy mechanisms that will make the next renewable standard sustainable and effective: 1. Make the renewable standard mandatory. Twenty-nine states have enacted mandatory renewable portfolio standards, while four other states have enacted voluntary renewable targets. A voluntary standard may appear to be more politically palatable, but it lacks the certainty utilities covet and the mandate utilities need to procure anything other than “least-cost” generation. 2. Include an alternative compliance payment (ACP) mechanism to clarify noncompliance. An ACP has been successfully implemented in most RPS states. Such a mechanism helps to establish an acceptable price for renewable generation in the state. If funds are generated through an ACP, they can be distributed to potentially viable energy technology projects. 3. Design requirements according to various state resources. The annual renewable generation requirements have been met by most RPS states. The benefit of these state standards is that they can be tailored to local resources. Set-asides, such as those for hog and poultry in North Carolina, can be used to address state-specific resources, expertise, and industry. 4. Allow energy efficiency programs and out-of-state renewable credits to meet some portion of renewable standard. The energy efficiency provision gives electricity retailers greater flexibility to meet the standard and gives greater control of assets. The out-of-state renewable credits enable the purchase of low-cost renewable generation that still meets broader emissions reduction goals. However, these advantages need to be balanced against the local economic interest of keeping resources in state and focused on renewable energy. Conclusion A renewable portfolio standard is a proven policy tool that can help to guide our transition away from fossil fuels. The lessons learned from other RPS programs, from North Carolina’s recent and pioneering effort, and from on-the-ground, local stakeholders, can and should be used to help other southern states to adopt an RPS. This will in turn help them to meet their energy needs, to diversify their energy sources, and to mitigate climate change.Item Open Access China's Natural Gas Imports and Prospects(2014-04-18) Tang, TingtingThe project provides an overview of China’s current natural gas imports and key factors impacting its future imports. As part of its strategy to pursue cleaner energy sources, the Chinese government has pledged to consume more natural gas, which has historically been underrepresented in the country’s energy mix. To achieve its natural gas consumption goal, China’s demand for imported natural gas is expected to reach 124 billion cubic meters in 2020, more than tripling its imports in 2012 of 38 billion cubic meters. Cheap and abundant gas in the U.S., as a result of the shale gas revolution, has generated enormous interest in China about the possibility of importing LNG from the U.S. However, uncertainties surrounding U.S. natural gas export policies reinforced China’s impression that importing gas from the U.S. may be a difficult and prolonged process. Several studies predict that the future influx of gas from the U.S. into the international market will lead to a decline in natural gas prices worldwide. As a result, even if China does not import LNG from the U.S., it is likely to benefit from the decrease in LNG prices in the global market. The mere possibility of importing gas from the U.S. has given China more leverage in its negotiations with Russia over the China-Russia gas pipeline. Given the recent progress the two countries have made in their negotiations, it is expected that Russia and China will finalize the gas pipeline agreement by the end of 2014. By 2020, the pipeline is expected to deliver 68 billion cubic meters of gas annually from Russia to China, meeting more than half of China’s total demand for imported gas. A secured supply of pipeline gas from Russia may depress China’s appetite for LNG imports from additional sources including the U.S. In addition, China’s domestic factors – including the gas tariff mechanism and regulations on import rights and infrastructure – will impact its future LNG imports. The current state-mandated gas tariff mechanism in China has led to losses of gas importing companies, since the mandated gas prices are not sufficient to cover the costs of imported gas. High barriers for any non-state capital to enter the gas-importing sector have further hindered efficient investments made along the LNG import value chain. Favorable regulatory reforms will incentivize Chinese companies, in particular non-state enterprises, to pursue cheaper natural gas supplies overseas, thereby increasing China’s competitiveness as a gas importer in the international market.Item Open Access Designing Clean Electricity Standards to Balance Costs, Benefits and Equity(2013-04-22) Isaacs, JessicaItem Open Access Domestic Content Requirements and India’s Solar Mission(2013-04-26) Fickling, MeeraDomestic content requirements are widely-used policies that require a specified proportion of a good to be produced within a certain jurisdiction. Applied to solar cells and modules procured through India's national solar power program, this policy is part of India's strategy to build a domestic manufacturing base for solar components and attain energy independence. However, a loophole in the requirement appears to have undermined its effectiveness. This paper uses a conceptual model and a set of probit and logit regressions to determine the effect of India's domestic content requirement for solar cells and modules on domestic manufacturing and technology choice. It finds that the requirement has done much less to spur domestic manufacturing than the Indian government envisioned.Item Open Access Item Open Access Electric Generation Investment in a Time of Natural Gas Price and Carbon Pricing Uncertainty: A Modeling Analysis(2013-04-16) Fitzpatrick, KristopherLow current and forecasted natural gas prices are spurring investment in new gas-fired electric generation in the eastern United States. In both regulated territories and organized electricity markets, natural gas power is beginning to displace significant amounts of retiring coal generation. However, the market price of natural gas has historically been volatile and unpredictable. If gas prices rise substantially from current forecasts in the next two decades, will customers face sharply higher electricity prices? What if a carbon tax accompanies this outcome? This modeling analysis sheds light on these questions by modeling long-term capacity expansion based on current assumptions, and then assessing how economic dispatch in three regions - the Southeast, PJM Interconnection, and ISO New England – will respond to alternate versions of future gas prices and carbon taxes. The results indicate that heavily gas-dependent regions like ISO New England would absorb the imposition of a carbon tax without major electricity price increases, but that it would face substantial price increases with sustained, elevated natural gas prices. The results also suggest that portfolios in the Southeast and PJM will skew more heavily to natural gas generation in the future if investment decisions are made under current conditions and assumptions. If this occurs, these two regions could face sharp electricity price increases with either higher-than-expected natural gas prices or the imposition of a carbon tax.Item Open Access Essays in Energy and Environmental Economics(2018) Prest, Brian CharlesThis dissertation includes three papers discussing different aspects of environmental and energy economics and policy. The first paper ("Peaking Interest: How awareness drives the effectiveness of time-of-use electricity pricing") analyzes what factors drive consumer responses to time-of-use electricity pricing. Such pricing is an increasingly common policy that is designed to reduce reliance on high-cost, inefficient, and often polluting power plants. Using both survey and meter data on Irish households, I find that behavioral factors drive consumer responses: consumer awareness and information are key to inducing responses, and marginal prices have minimal effects.
The second paper ("Prices versus Quantities with Policy Updating", with William Pizer) is a theoretical study considering how intertemporal trading ("banking") under cap-and-trade style policies changes the traditional trade-off between price and quantity regulation (Weitzman 1974). Our theoretical model illustrates an unappreciated advantage of quantity regulation: expected policy updates are incorporated immediately through secondary markets via a no arbitrage condition. This helps us understand the welfare implications of observed price volatility in permit markets and has implications for the design of environmental regulations, such as the debate over the relative merits of a carbon tax versus "cap and trade'' policy.
The third paper ("Trophy Hunting vs. Manufacturing Energy: The Price Responsiveness of Shale Gas", with Richard Newell and Ashley Vissing) uses well-level data to estimate how the shale revolution has changed the price responsiveness of U.S. natural gas supply. We find that U.S. natural gas supply is approximately three times more price responsive as a result of the shale revolution, owing entirely to higher production per well. This improves our understanding of the market dynamics around natural gas supply.
Each of these papers has implications for environmental and energy policy. The first paper aims to understand how to improve the effectiveness of time-of-use electricity pricing policies. The second paper addresses an important feature of climate policy design, given high observed volatility in carbon allowance prices in the United States and Europe. The third paper aims to improve understanding of the recent changes in U.S. natural gas markets, with important implications for the fuel mix in electricity generation (in particular, coal-fired versus gas-fired generation) and hence CO2 emissions.
Item Open Access Essays in Energy and Environmental Economics(2022) Harris, Robert IsaacPolicymakers are increasingly turning to second- or third-best policy interventions targeted to specific sectors of the economy for mitigating pollution and climate damages despite long-standing agreement among economists that pricing pollution externalities is the efficient (and hence first-best) solution. The essays composing this dissertation explore the rationale for such policy preferences by measuring the environmental benefits of one such policy intervention and evaluating the expected welfare outcomes of calibrated pollution pricing policies. In particular, the first two chapters examine the efficiency and equity implications of rooftop solar policy, an example of a targeted intervention in the electricity sector. The final chapter discusses what appears to be a policy preference for including emission targets in climate policy and then presents an alternative welfare metric that both rationalizes the desire for an emissions target and allows us to evaluate different "hybrid tax" policies.
In the first chapter, "Distributional Benefits of Rooftop Solar Capacity," my co-author Travis Dauwalter and I study the equity and environmental justice implications of rooftop solar policy in the U.S. It is an accepted fact today that households of color and low-income households face disproportionate exposure to pollution and poor environmental conditions. The effects of environmental policies on improving or perhaps even worsening the pollution gap are less understood, however. We provide the first robust evidence on the distribution of benefits of rooftop solar capacity, contributing to the growing economics literature on environmental justice and the distributional consequences of policy. We find the current distribution of environmental benefits from rooftop solar is regressive, but that households of color receive slightly larger benefits per capita than White households. Most interestingly, we demonstrate the lack of an efficiency-equity tradeoff in this context: rooftop solar capacity allocations that maximize total environmental benefits also maximize benefits received by households of color and low-income households. Our results suggest that current rooftop solar policy, reflected at least in part by existing capacity, fails to achieve policymakers’ desired distributional outcomes and could be better targeted to achieve more efficient and more equitable allocations.
The second chapter, "Heterogeneous Solar Capacity Benefits, Appropriability, and the Costs of Suboptimal Siting," co-authored with Steven Sexton, Justin Kirkpatrick, and Nicholas Muller provides the foundation for the first chapter. In this paper, we provide the first zip-code level estimates of the environmental benefits of rooftop solar capacity by estimating marginal power plant emissions responses to changes in electricity load. We use these estimates to compute the total environmental benefits of rooftop solar and show that about $1 billion in benefits would be gained annually were capacity optimally sited. Together, these chapters demonstrate that current solar policy cannot be rationalized on either efficiency or equity grounds.
In the third chapter, "Using Carbon Taxes to Meet an Emission Target," my co-author Billy Pizer and I explore emissions and cost outcomes of simple, rule-based hybrid carbon tax policies, contributing to a growing literature on carbon tax adjustment mechanisms. This work is particularly important as current policy debate in the U.S. has frequently discussed the ability (or inability) of carbon taxes to achieve certainty over emissions outcomes. We show that simple adjustment mechanisms can achieve substantial increases in emissions certainty relative to an ordinary, exogenous tax.
Item Open Access Three Essays in Energy and Environmental Economics(2019) LI, YatingThis dissertation is a collection of three essays in the field of environmental and energy economics. While each essay addresses different questions, they all contribute to the understanding of environment or energy economics related to energy demand using empirical analyses. The first two papers focus on domestic energy demand modeling and forecasting; one highlights the importance of appliance adoption with income growth, and the other estimates the impact of climate change on electricity consumption in China.
The trend of energy demand growth applies to not only China but also the developing countries in the Southeast Asia region. To meet the rapid increase in energy demand, most countries built coal-fired power plants though cleaner options such as solar and wind technologies are getting cheaper. The involvement of Chinese finance into coal-fired power plants is controversial and often leads to concerns on environmental outcomes and carbon footprints. Hence, in the third paper, I examine the environmental impact of coal-fired power plants China financed overseas.
The first paper (“Chinese residential electricity consumption estimation and forecast using micro-data”, with Jing Cao, Mun Sing Ho, Richard G. Newell, and William A. Pizer) was published in Resource and Energy Economics in 2017. Based on econometric estimation using data from the Chinese Urban Household Survey, we develop a preferred forecast range of 85 to 143 percent growth in residential per capita electricity demand over 2009 to 2025. Our analysis suggests that per capita income growth drives a 43% increase, with the remainder due to an unexplained time trend. Roughly one-third of the income-driven demand comes from increases in the stock of specific major appliances, particularly AC units. The other two-thirds comes from non-specific sources of income-driven growth and is based on an estimated income elasticity that falls from 0.28 to 0.14 as income rises. While the stock of refrigerators is not projected to increase, we find that they contribute nearly 20 percent of household electricity demand. Alternative plausible time trend assumptions are responsible for the wide range of 85 to 143 percent. Meanwhile we estimate a price elasticity of demand of -0.7. These estimates point to carbon pricing and appliance efficiency policies that could substantially reduce demand.
The second paper turns attention from income growth to climate change. Estimating the impacts of climate change on energy use across the globe is essential for analysis of both mitigation and adaptation policies. Yet existing empirical estimates are concentrated in western countries, especially the United States. In the second paper (“Climate change and residential electricity consumption in the Yangtze River Delta, China”, with William A. Pizer and Libo Wu), we use daily data on household electricity demand to estimate how electricity demand would change in Shanghai in the context of climate change. For colder days below 7 degree C, a 1 degree C increase in daily temperature reduces electricity demand by 2.8%. On warm days above 25 degree C, a 1 degree C increase in daily temperatures leads to a 14.5% increase in electricity consumption. As income increases, households’ weather sensitivity remains the same for hotter days in the summer but increases during the winter.
We use this estimated behavior in conjunction with a collection of downscaled global climate models (GCMs) to construct a relationship between future annual global mean surface temperature (GMST) changes and annual residential electricity demand. We find that annual electricity demand increases by 9.3% per +1 degree C in annual GMST. In comparison, peak daily electricity use increases by as much as 36.3% per +1 degree C in annual GMST, almost four times the average electricity increase. Though most accurate for Shanghai, our findings could be most credibly extended to the urban areas in the Yangtze River Delta, covering roughly one-fifth of China’s urban population and one-fourth of GDP. The second paper was published in the Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America (PNAS) in 2018.
While the first two papers focus on domestic energy demand in China and use micro data sets, the third paper (“Environmental Impact of overseas coal-fired power plants financed by China”) examines the infrastructure support to energy consumption, i.e. power plants, and their environmental outcomes. Using satellite measures, we first show that the SO2 increased substantially after the operation of the power plants. We further compared the performance of coal plants financed by China with the rest of coal plants in the region. Due to the small number of Chinese-financed plants that started operating during the period of 2006-2016, we have only limited results from our comparison of Chinese and non-Chinese financed plants. We find no significant difference in SO2 impact in general, but observe higher SO2 increase after operation for the ones financed by China among the plants using subcritical technologies and lower for those using supercritical technologies, though not significantly different from the rest. Among plants larger than 500 MW, the percentage of supercritical power plants among Chinese financed coal plants is higher than the rest.
Item Open Access U.S.-China Solar Trade War: Economic and Political Implications of the 2012 and 2014 Antidumping Disputes(2014-12-08) Darby, MartaFollowing the 2011 flood of Chinese solar photovoltaic (PV) panels, SolarWorld and a conglomerate of six unnamed U.S. solar cell and module manufacturers filed a lawsuit in October 2011 against Chinese producers alleging that they were receiving unfair government subsidies and were selling their products into the U.S. market for less than fair market value. The artificially low-priced solar products, SolarWorld explained, would materially harm the U.S. solar manufacturing industry, an industry that already was struggling. By mid-2012, the U.S. Department of Commerce (USDOC) and U.S. International Trade Commission (USITC) had imposed preliminary duties ranging from 31% to 250% on Chinese solar cells and the modules that contained them; ultimately, the agencies affirmed these duties in November 2012. The dispute divided the U.S. solar industry. Manufacturers argued that the duties were necessary to protect U.S. manufacturing, jobs, and fair competition. Meanwhile, U.S. installers claimed that the duties would put the brakes on the installation sector and the many jobs it promised. Still others surmised that the duties would have little effect. After all, Chinese producers had an easy out: thanks to the solar cell loophole, they could simply produce modules with foreign solar cells and ship them into the U.S. market duty free. This analysis explores how the antidumping dispute may have shaped the U.S. import market and the U.S. industry, including domestic PV manufacturers and installers. It finds that despite the solar cell loophole, the dispute may have created opportunities for emerging partners to enter (or re-enter) the U.S. market and, perhaps, increased the price of solar cells and modules for U.S. buyers. Any such effects, however, must be understood in the context of the industry as a whole: booming installation markets, changing policy, and rising new players. With the dispute still ongoing, many chapters likely remain untold.